Monday, December 04, 2017

Cryptocurrencies, initial coin offerings (ICO's) and tokens: we remain puppets on someone else's strings !

Screenshot www.flippening.watch 
Now that the bitcoin price is heading towards $10K and beyond, we see another wave of interest in the cryptocurrency domain. Regulators warn about the risk of Initial Coin Offerings and news bulletins keep on re-discussing what is happening in this space.

It's a matter of private currencies and tokens
What we are looking at in the cryptocurrency, blockchain and distributed ledger space is that seemingly public and democratic technologies are being put to work for specific groups of individuals/companies. While the technology may be sold as serving a public purpose, in the end it's just a variation of any medieval local Duke issuing his private currencies to the population: profits to the Duke and potential losses to the public.

What is happening now is a convolution of low interest rate regime, overhyped media and greed, leading to private individuals scrambling for profits in the area of cryptocurrencies. They can do this either by investing in the cryptocurrencies themselves or as an entrepreneur by sharing a mining pool, setting up exchange's or trade functions or developing new token types or blockchains. And as with the gold rush, it will be the sellers of shovels and buckets that will in the end really make the profit.

Beware: we remain puppets on a string
While in the initial stages of the bitcoin blockchain, we could see a whole lot of alt-coin scams, we are now seeing a range of ICO-scams, as people are exploiting the ethereum capabilities to venture out in the cryptocurrency world. Only a very few of those will survive and the rest will disappear just as the nonsense alt-coins did.

So, whoever participates in cryptocurrencies or ICOs deliberately hands in governance to an unknown constellation of companies and individuals. Or as I put it in this 2013-blog:
The redistribution of value that can occurs with these new currencies may look democratic, but that is a wolfe in sheep' s clothes. Effectively the new currencies are and will be the domain of private individuals trying to seek private gain rather than anything else. And there is no guarantee whatsoever that this constellation will have the interests at heart of all people in society. 
It will be Darwins' survival of the fittest all over again, which will exclude certain groups of citizens from participating fully in society. As democratic as a crowdbased currency looks: you will still be a puppet but on a different string, with unknown gains being made by unknown players in the value chain of this collective currency. 

To bubble or not to bubble? 
The question that is now on the public table: is the value of bitcoin a bubble as the tulipomania? Despite the tendency to say yes, I would argue that the answer could effectively be no.

First of all, the whole western money system is a bubble right now, as central banks have inflated our financial systems to an enormous degree with the Quantitative Easing. We should realize that neither bitcoin nor any other good in this society has its proper value right now. Thanks to these central banks, the amount of money that I get in my savings account has been too low for almost a decade now.

Second, within this skewed monetary world, market-forces do still apply. They will also apply to bitcoin-core so that with each fork (bcash) or new blockchain (ethereum, eos) a potential new competitor may turn out to become the winner. The word used for a shift in this momentum is: the flippening (as sentiment may flip to different assets or infrastructures in a very brief moment of time).

The interesting thing is of course, that in this digital world, anyone can monitor this real-time on sites such as Flippening Watch. It will be like watching the strings of the puppets move, without knowing who the real players are.

Sunday, November 12, 2017

Why some countries started using cheques and others chose giro

These days I am busy writing a book on the history of Dutch retail payments. The focus of the book is on the dynamics of the Netherlands, without the aim to compare with other countries or to explain country differences. Still, the process leads to some observations that I would like to share as they may be useful for other researchers in the field.

What explains the origins of giro and cheque countries?
One of the basic facts in retail payments is that there is a structural difference between so-called giro-countries (Austria, Switzerland, Japan, Germany, Netherlands, Belgium etc) and cheque-countries (France, US, Canada, Australia).

In his excellent dissertation on payments and network effects, Gottfried Leibbrandt sets out to answer this question. After a thorough investigation of literature, he concludes that network effects are an important factor that helps explain the typical development path per country. At the same time, he finds it hard to trace the origin of the difference between cheque- and giro-countries
1. There is no satisfying explanation for the country differences. Empirical studies find that country idiosyncrasies rather than variables like GDP and crime explain the differences in instrument usage.

In a similar vein, the first BIS working group on Retail Payments observes:
Use of different retail payment instruments in the so-called cheque countries and giro countries can be explained by the differences in: 
• concentration of market supply among traditional providers of retail payment services; 
• financial incentives for providers with respect to debit and credit transfers; 
• nature of the risks in the value transfer processes for the two types of payments; and 
• legal framework and regulatory environment.
Of course the above list is long enough to be right and the report also mentions numerous French regulations that influenced its use, in particular also the rule that payment with cheques should be free to the people. And indeed this legal factor must not be forgotten.

Where is the cheque in the Netherlands?
In the Netherlands, a well functioning system of so-called cashiers notes existed, alongside regular cash for quite some time. Then in 1814, the establishment of the central bank and the introduction of bank notes introduced competition for the cashiers. In the early 1830s one of the cashiers fought a heavy legal battle to preserve the use of its cashiers notes, but eventually gave in to the reality that the bank notes were becoming the standard.

Ever since, the central bank was careful not to obstruct the cashiers and bankers too much in their business operations. So as a practical measure, the central bank took care to set its fees for deposits and discounted bills of exchange at a less competitive rate than the market. But fact of the matter remains that a possible candidate for a privately issued Dutch payment cheque, was no longer available.

Some parliamentary proceedings suggest that the legal rules with respect to bills of exchange 'wissels' were insufficient to really create a sound basis for the use of cheques as a payment instrument. As a result the market used bank notes in combination with clearing arrangements.

This intrigued me so when looking for more information on the topic I encountered a college book (by Mr. W. Molengraaf) that suddenly shed more light on the situation in other countries.


What Molengraaff states is that cheques came into existence in the United Kingdom as 'sight-bills' on a banker. They were brought into circulation as an alternative payment instrument to circumvent the stamp duty that would apply to a regular bill of exchange. He continues to state that also in France the cheques owe their existence solely to tax considerations.

Up next I figured I would take a look at a US stamp duty register from 1866. And we can indeed see the difference there. A bank check would cost 2 cents, regardless of the sum involved, while a bill of exchange would cost 5 cents and possibly more when higher amounts were involved.



To me it's clear that stamp duty may well be an important part of the puzzle, explaining the difference between giro and cheque-countries. But we should add an analysis of market structure, competing instruments to complete the picture.

The particular Dutch situation.... 
In the Dutch situation we will see that the discussion on setting up postal giro services started around 1902, already with references to the situation in other countries. It took us more than 10 years to decide on the establishment of the postal giro services and indeed market structure and some regulatory capture may have influenced the discussion. Also it became pretty clear that the incumbent bankers and cashiers did not want to move forward with their own version of bankers giro. But that's stuff for a next blog.

In the mean time, if you enjoyed this blog, you may want to let me know that you're interested to be informed when my book on hundred years of Dutch giro payments will be published. This will help you understand more of the intertwined dynamics that are at work when retail payment systems and instruments are developed.

Just send an e-mail here and I will notify you when the book is coming up.

Tuesday, October 17, 2017

DAO-fork at odds with Ethereum terms and conditions

Last month, Antonio Madeire nicely summarized the discussion on the DAO-hack and the fork which brought Ethereum classic into being. I remember that my contribution to the discussion at that time was that the Ethereum developer community should not revert to a hard fork but to the judge and/or arbitration.

Governance and terms and conditions
The other day, I was discussing with Ian Grigg, a long time mutual topic of interest: making technology work by adding proper arbitration to smart contracts and agreements. This can even be done in code, as he had demonstrated way back in the 1990s in his ricardo system.

This prompted me to actually take a look at the Ethereum terms and references to see what it said about disputes. Well, have a look yourselves:

All disputes or claims arising out of, relating to, or in connection with the Terms, the breach thereof, or use of the Ethereum Platform shall be finally settled under the Rules of Arbitration of the International Chamber of Commerce by one or more arbitrators appointed in accordance with said Rules. All claims between the parties relating to these Terms that are capable of being resolved by arbitration, whether sounding in contract, tort, or otherwise, shall be submitted to ICC arbitration...... 

.... And so on.

What does this mean for Ethereum governance?
While I hugely appreciate the development of Ethereum and all the efforts that have gone into it. it does strike me that when push came to shove, the developers brushed aside their own terms and conditions. The use of Ethereum was instrumental to setting up the DAO, so why not revert to the ICC Arbitration?

My guess would be that, not being lawyers or into governance, the developers used the tools that came in handy and quickly. Alternatively, it might be the case that they might have invested in the DAO themselves quite considerably.

Regardless of the exact reasons behind not using the dispute resolution mechanism, the paradox is that, while there is a formal basis for dispute resolution under Ethereum, the likelihood exists that in future instances of trouble, the developers will again fork their way out of trouble.

Create an additional dispute resolution layer.
Any practical use and implementation of Ethereum should therefore come accompanied with additional agreements on dispute resolution, so that organisations that cooperate on the basis of the ethereum blockchain create their own governance basis.

Thursday, September 21, 2017

Ceci n'est pas une 'payment instrument': a reflection on fuel cards and the PSD2

In september this year, the FCA published its policy statement and approach document on the PSD2. I've been eagerly watching this document to find out what their final take would be on the understanding of the limited network exemption in relation to the specific nature of fuel cards. Because there is more than meets the eye here.

In essence, some fuel cards effectively function as a purchase button on a website. They don't initiate payment orders at all. They would thus fall outside of the PSD2-scope, as any other shopping-button on websites. Due to a twist of faith however, the bank supervisors seem to be keen to ignore this reality for fuel cards and bring those under the PSD2.

In this post I will highlight the flaws in this approach and conclude that the result is that if all regulators start re-writing the definitions themselves, we better label the PSD2 the Purchase Service Directive (see also the full  and more elaborate analysis on the subject here).

Background
In the original payment services directive article 3k provided for a proportional application of the PSD1. Instruments with a limited geographical reach and scope, such as store cards and fuel cards were not subject to its provisions. The exemption 3k) was thus called the limited network exemption.
3 (k) services based on instruments that can be used to acquiregoods or services only in the premises used by the issuer orunder a commercial agreement with the issuer either withina limited network of service providers or for a limited rangeof goods or services;
In its proposal for the new version of the PSD, the Commission claimed the existence of payments systems, waivered as “limited networks” with massive volumes, which imply greater risk and no legal protection for payment users as “feedback from the market”. However, this feedback was not really a result of the external impact analysis onthe economic impact of the PSD1

What could be seen though is that the interpretations of local supervisors ranged from strict to very lenient, which distorted the playing field in Europe. In addition, some observers noted that there was a strong desire by supervisors to have stricter rules for in particular the fuel cards market (see the mystery of unregulated massive payment volumes, as discussed in the Paysysreport of March 2014).

In the end, the net result was a very strict version of article 3k in the PSD2, to ensure that its future application would be for truly limited networks only. In addition, any organisation that uses this specific exemption has to notify the supervisor. But let's take a good look at the pre-amble and the exemption text.

The definitions
The pre-amble states that payment instruments covered by the limited network exclusion could include store cards and fuel cards, but it isn't conclusive. They could, but they could also not.
(14) Payment instruments covered by the limited network exclusion could include store cards, fuel cards, membership cards, public transport cards, parking ticketing, meal vouchers or vouchers for specific services, which are sometimes subject to a specific tax or labour legal framework designed to promote the use of such instruments to meet the objectives laid down in social legislation.
Where such a specific-purpose instrument develops into a general purpose instrument, the exclusion from the scope of this Directive should no longer apply. Instruments which can be used for purchases in stores of listed merchants should not be excluded from the scope of this Directive as such instruments are typically designed for a network of service providers which is continuously growing. The limited network exclusion should apply in combination with the obligation of potential payment service providers to notify activities falling within its scope.
Article 3k is actually more clear, certainly in comparison to the previous version. It now refers explicitly to services based on specific payment instruments
(k) services based on specific payment instruments that can be used only in a limitedway, that meet one of the following conditions:

  • (i) instruments allowing the holder to acquire goods or services only in the premises of the issuer or within a limited network of service providers under direct commercial agreement with a professional issue;
  • (ii) instruments which can be used only to acquire a very limited range of goods or services;
  • (iii) instruments valid only in a single Member State provided at the request of an undertaking or a public sector entity and regulated by a national or regional public authority for specific social or tax purposes to acquire specific goods or services from suppliers having a commercial agreement with the issuer; 

The legal conclusion is thus: first you need to have something that is a payment instrument and then it may fall under a limited network exemption. 

The FCA's approach: let's not be clear about the payment adjective
The above may not be how the FCA are looking at it. Both in their consultation and further guidance they seem to that 3k is written as pertaining to all instruments, not just payment instruments. I pointed this out in a response to the consultation (see this separate blog) and asked for further clarification.

Yet, their feedback document, doesn't mention anything on this definition question at all, which is a bit disappointing given the timely and good job efforts that the FCA usually put in with all their consultation work. So the ambiquity stays: while the notification forms clearly outline that applications must clarify the nature of the involved payment services and payment instruments, all the guidance does is steer towards an understanding of the 3k article as pertaining to all instrument (as under PSD1). 

This still leaves us with the question: when would a fuel card qualify as a a payment instrument. Or is it just as exempt from the PSD as a purchase button in an Internet-webstore? 

Fuel card as a payment instrument or purchase device?
Let’s have a closer look at the workings of a fuel card and what it does in terms of business processes. Generally speaking, fuel cards are delivered by oil companies to corporate fleet owners, sometimes distributed via resellers or co-branding arrangements. They effectively are a tool that validates the legal competency of its holder, to take out goods/services from service delivery stations.

The company to which the cards are provided takes full responsibility for all services/goods delivered to the users of the cards and receives a monthly overview of all purchases done with the cards. It can set usage levels per card, ensuring that no more than a certain amount of goods and services are to be delivered to the cardholder. It can also set the range of goods to be delivered from narrow (fuel only) to wide (fuel and shop goods).

Every month, the fleet owning company receives an invoice with an overview of all purchases made and the rebate applied (mostly volume based). This specifies the purchases made in the network of the oil company itself as well as those in other networks and by other service providers. These other networks of service stations may also deliver goods/services to the card holder. What happens in practice is that prior to the actual delivery, the cardholders’ oil-company buys the whole service/goods package that the card-holder wishes to take out at the selected other networks with whom the oil-company has struck delivery and service agreements.

This results in a chain sale of goods/services from:
-              the service station dealer to its country organisation,
-              the service station country organisation to the oil company national organisation
-              the oil company in a country to the corporate client that distributed its cards to the employees.
While technically there may be many variations to this flow, it does serve to achieve an important effect in VAT-terms. It allows the involved oil companies and networks to reclaim the relevant VAT from local authorities and thus lower the end-fee to the corporate fleet-owners.

What's the difference between purchase and payment?
In the table below, I've summarized the functional difference between the use of a payment card or a purchase card at an oil station.

Using a purchase tool
Using a payment instrument
Used to instruct the retailer or service station to deliver goods/services
Used to instruct the bank to make a payment to a third party bank account
The amount to be paid is unknown. At the end of the month, rebates are applied and the reconstruction of what the actual equivalent price at this moment of sale would have been, is always a mathematic reconstruction.
The amount to be paid is clear.
Authentication of the card holder equals the right to receive goods/services up to a certain threshold
Authentication of the card holder equals the digital signature of the payment transfer
Positive response by oil company equals the formal sale of the services/goods from service station to oil company and the mandate to provide the services/goods to the card holder
Positive response equals the proper processing of the payment instruction
Holder of purchase instrument is not (by definition) authorised to give payment orders that relate to the billing account of the fleet owner
Holder of instrument is by design authorised to give payment orders from that account to the payees account
Holder only receives proof of purchase / delivery but not proof of payment
Holder receives proof of payment and possibly also proof of purchase
No cash-back possible
Cash back might be possible under the rules of the cards-account
Oil company may design its own purchase, control and billing procedures, use its own set of purchase tools and may set its own acceptance and risk parameters. Intercompany delivery agreements will apply.
Card is a payment instrument and payment transactions with it fall under legislation (PSD) and payment brand regulation, with bank specific acceptance and risk parameters
VAT-recovered and rebate applied to purchases by all cardholders of the fleet-owner
VAT-recovery not included
Aggregated invoice for goods and services delivered, sent to the corporate treasurer of the fleet owner, and paid for using the direct debit instrument
Periodic account statement for payments made or (as in the case of credit cards): aggregated invoice for total value of payments made, followed by direct debit.

While the bank card ticks all the boxes, the fuel cards as outlined above, do not qualify as payment instruments under the current Payment Service Directive. There is no request being made to place, withdraw or transfer funds, hence there is no payment transaction, no payment order and no payment instrument. Hence, article 3k is nowhere close to being relevant. 

What will happen to the fuel cards niche?
As the editors of the Paysys report outlined earlier in March 2014, there may exist a hidden regulatory agenda in Europe to capture fuel cards under the 3k article of the PSD2.

This seems to be exactly the discussion right now for the relevant stakeholders around this subject in Europe. While technically the legal argument is straightforward, leading to fuel cards being out of scope, some lawyers point to the spirit of the article or the statements of regulators (in whichever respect being made) to claim that fuel cards do fall under article 3k and require notification.

As in many situations, it's not the final legal analysis that is relevant but the legal uncertainty. Arguing the above case with a regulator may take too much time and is not the preferred option for risk-averse large issuers of fuel cards. So we may well see some players in the oil industry ending up not arguing their legal case and abiding with a flawed regulator view that takes fuel cards into the exemption scope of PSD2.

The wider implications: Payment Service Directive becomes Purchase Services Directive
If the fuel card case is not being challenged in courts, it sets an interesting precedent. Because in essence, there is no analytical difference between the fuel card and PIN mentioned above and the user-id / password combination that is in use by retail customers that are shopping at websites, using purchase buttons. Both tools are and should be out of scope for a payment service regulator. Just arguing that the instrument looks to much like a payment instrument is just not enough. Ceci n'est pas une pipe 'payment instrument'.

Forgetting the adjective 'payments' in article 3k means that the second Payments Services Directive may well turn into a full swing Purchase Services Directive. And by the looks of it, this is what the FCA may be doing in the fuel cards niche right now. This leaves the rest of the market wondering if their niches may follow at some point in time. 

Supervisors should however not cross that Rubicon and avoid transforming the PSD2 into a Purchase Services Directive. They should stick to the legal definition and if they don't like the consequence should not take justice in their own hands by forgetting adjectives that stand in the way of their (hidden) agenda's.  

Let commerce be commerce and payments be payments. 

Tuesday, August 01, 2017

Dutch central bank can further encourage innovation for payment institutions with a quick win

Article 18.2 in PSD2 (Article 15 in PSD1) on the nature of funds
 in a payment account of a payment institution

It's a logical thing. As the bakery provides bread, banks provide loans and allow savings, e-money institutions offer e-money, payment institutions are allowed to provide payment accounts to their customers. These accounts would neither be redeemable deposits or repayable funds, nor e-money, as the article in the PSD(2) states.

Stricter interpretation by De Nederlandsche Bank 
De Nederlandsche Bank, our local supervisor, however does not appear to allow the above flavour in the Netherlands easily. Companies that have business models in which payment accounts (whether with or without IBAN) are offered, should not be surprised if they are told that the funds would qualify either as redeemable deposits or e-money, with little inbetween.

 As a result, one will not encounter a lot of payment-account issuing by payment institutions in the Netherlands. And this is in spite of the fact that even the Explanatory Memorandum of our Financial Supervision Act explicitly mentioned this possibility.

Other supervisors follow the EU-approach 
Thus we can see issuers from other countries, such as Pocopay from Estonia, offer payment services and payment accounts to students where these can't be offered by local players. On their website, we see this issuer outlining (USING CAPITALS) in the terms and conditions that the funds are not redeemable, to be used for payments and not covered by deposit insurance of any kind.

Other instances can be found in German or French markets, leading to the situation that Dutch payment institutions are restrained in product innovation and less able to compete with PIs from other countries, which may offer a broader solution range to their customers.

Quick win to facilitate innovation in payments in the Netherlands 
There is a clear quick win here in the Netherlands in terms of payment regulation. Instead of claiming that funds are either deposits or e-money, De Nederlandsche Bank should more easily allow payment institutions to also offer the third flavour: non-redeemable funds on payment accounts, used for payment purposes.

Of course, one could raise the question whether it is possible to make such a business model work, but it should be the market that decides rather than the supervisor.

This article is a translation of a contribution to the Financieel Dagblad of July 29, 2017.

Wednesday, June 21, 2017

Adyen: the new bank is not a bank any more

City giro Amsterdam: not a bank, but nice picture and looks like one
Source: City Archive Amsterdam
Dutch bank registers show that, since the end of April this year, Dutch payment institution Adyen has officially acquired a banking license. This is clearly part of a bigger picture that shows ICT-based companies moving in a similar direction. Many years ago we could already witness the e-money institution Paypal become a bank in Luxembourg. Most recently Klarna also turned from payments institution to a bank. Now what could be driving these companies towards the bank license?

A ‘payments bank’
A closer look at the register tells us that Adyen is licensed for: taking deposits, providing loans, payment services, issuance and management of other payment instruments, foreign currency and issuance of e-money. I would call this a ‘payments bank’ as it demonstrates a clear focus on facilitating payments rather than covering all financial services (which is the case for challenger bank Bunq).

The move towards a bank does of course mean that own capital needs to be increased and some further obligations kick in, such as registering for the deposit insurance scheme. Also, despite the focus on payments, Adyen will need to provide some loans, in order to fulfil the definition of a bank in the legal sense: taking deposits and providing loans.

Now, let’s also look at the further practical consequences:
a- scope discussions for payments solutioning,
b- connections to clearing and settlement,
c- counterparty risk for corporate customers.

a-scope discussions for payments solutioning
Payment institutions that operate under the Payment Services Directive always need to be aware of the nature of the services that they provider. Does it qualify as money remittance, executing payments, executing payments with a credit line or placing money on an account? For each customer that seeks a bespoke solution to a business problem, the service offering needs to be qualified and business rules need to be applied accordingly. Banks on the other hand can more easily engage in the solution domain, given that any setup that involves holding funds and transferring those, will be possible under that license.

Now, payments institutions may of course be well accustomed to the scope and qualification work, so at the end of the day, this part of new business development may not be the source of a lot of head-ache. Still, it might be helpful to bring an end to discussions with local supervisors in Europe that might have their own opinions on the exact content of the payments institution license.

b-connections to clearing and settlement
One big difference between banks and payment institutions is that payment institutions are barred access from the RTGS-system of the ECB. The reasons is that the Settlement Finality Directive does not allow for PIs to become a direct member of designated systems. Even though already 5 years ago, the Dutch Ministry of Finance has made it clear that from a policy perspective the Settlement Finality Directive should change in this respect, no further action can be seen on the EU-level.

This is remarkable, as it is clear that we have a deep market for payment institutions, in which values of funds flow (or future funds flow) that may be quite significant. For example, the € 80 billion value of transactions that flow annually via Adyen (2016) comes close to the total value of transactions at the Dutch point of sale which is somewhere near the € 100 billion mark. There seems to be little logic to exclude these flows via payment institutions, from the scope of the Settlement Finality Directive.

In addition, we should not forget that the prohibition to have an account in TARGET2 has an impact on the future instant payment schemes as well. The settlement leg of most instant payment schemes will be organised in such a manner that only participants with access to TARGET2 can be direct members. The implicit competitive advantage of direct access to clearing and settlement is thus carried over into the new world of instant payments as well. Unless of course, the payment institution should choose to become a bank (or the settlement finality directive changes).

c-counterparty risk to corporate customers
In the classic design of a payment institution, the PI holds the customer funds in a separated account at a financial institution. Yet, if the bank where those monies are held goes broke, there is no recourse to the funds whatsoever. So the PI-business model means that all corporate customers have an inherent counterparty risk against the bank(s) that the PI has chosen to use to channel the separated payment flows.

It is well known that in particular larger companies dislike such intermediate counterparty risks. We’ve witnessed this before when Kasbank in the Netherlands was the only settlement bank for the transactions at the stock exchange. That model was eventually phased out. 

In a similar vein I could imagine that the possibility to eliminate this counterparty risk for its customers, may have also been one of the considerations for Adyen to move towards a bank license. In addition, the increased capital base that comes with the bank status could also help in comforting corporate customers. For a company that processes so many transaction annually, the obliged minimum capital base of € 125.000 appears to be somewhat thin.

The new bank is not a bank any more
As the digitalisation of our economy allows for further modularisation of all kinds of services, we see the same thing happening in the financial sector. We can also witness banking and payments regulation adapt to this reality. The first wave of ‘bank-light’ regulation in 2002 allowed for e-money institutions and the second one in 2009 for payment institutions. In both categories the larger players have gradually chosen to obtain a banking license, while some players have started a digital bank from scratch.

With the renewal of the Payment Service Directive and its obligatory open access, it is clear that for payments services the modularisation of services has become the norm. And it may be only a matter of time before we see the other bank business lines open up all the same. With that, the mental image of the bank as a full service provider will gradually disappear. We will undoubtedly see many more new focused banks, such as Adyen, who each excel at their own game within the bank sector.

The new bank is not a bank anymore. 

Thursday, June 08, 2017

Response to FCA consultation: please clarify what will happen to the payment in 'payment instrument' in article 3k?

This April, the FCA launched its consultation on the Implementation of the revisedPayment Services Directive(PSD2): draft Approach Documentand draft Handbook changes. When reading this I was in particular paying close attention to the discussion of the limited network exemption in article 3k.

Background: limited network exemption
The limited network exemption has its background in the fact that many retailer-based shopping or payment solutions exist, that have a function similar to that of a payment, albeit on a local scale or for a limited range of goods. In order not to be burdened with a huge supervisory obligation, the regulator has taken this class of activities out of the scope of the Payment Service Directive and rightly so.

There is a relevant difference between providing EU wide, reachable payment instruments and solutions that solve a specific niche retailer problem. But getting this right in all detail is tough and therefore the wording of article 3k is somewhat vague.
(k) services based on instruments that can be used to acquire
goods or services only in the premises used by the issuer or
under a commercial agreement with the issuer either within
a limited network of service providers or for a limited range
of goods or services;
This allows supervisors to apply the article in a sensible way, in line with the spirit of the regulation.

Changes in PSD2: from instruments to payment instruments
The Paysys report of March 2014, describes the following on the evolution of the article:

In its final report on the PSD II (11 March 201412) the ECON Committee accepted the Recital 12 with the statement of the Commission of the existence of “massive payment volumes and values” offering “hundreds or thousands of different products and services” which are wrongfully operating under the exception of the limited networks of the Payment Services Directive (2007/64/EC). In order to improve consumer protection, these huge payment schemes should no longer be waivered.

Therefore, the Commission proposed a narrowed definition of “limited network/limited range” (Article 3 k) and a very restrictive implementation. In general, the ECON Committee followed the proposal of the Commission by taking over uncritically its assumption of the existence of non-regulated “massive payment volumes” in the market.

In phrasing the new article however, something did happen that may have been legally quite relevant. The wording instruments changed into payment instruments. This means that instruments which do not qualify as payment instruments and are not used to deliver payment services under the PSD2, will not qualify.

(k) services based on specific payment instruments that can be used only in a limited
way, that meet one of the following conditions:

  • (i) instruments allowing the holder to acquire goods or services only in the premises of the issuer or within a limited network of service providers under direct commercial agreement with a professional issue;
  • (ii) instruments which can be used only to acquire a very limited range of goods or services;
  • (iii) instruments valid only in a single Member State provided at the request of an undertaking or a public sector entity and regulated by a national or regional public authority for specific social or tax purposes to acquire specific goods or services from suppliers having a commercial agreement with the issuer; 

Effectively this takes out a lot of retailer instruments, which sometimes can be card-based, as they are not truly payment instruments but tools to add purchases into a shopping basket (which can be paid monthly via direct debit payment for example). It also means that petrol cards or fuel cards that are based on a similar mechanism - and may include a chain sale - will not fall under the exemption but can be considered out of scope.

Now, my personal guess is that while this legal consequence is clear, supervisors may want to ignore the relevant adjective 'payments' in order to keep their hold on near-payment mechanisms, even when they are not in scope of the PSD2 and do not fit under this definition. For that reason I was very interested to see what the FCA did with the difference between instruments and payment instruments.

What does the FCA propose to do with this?
It' turns out that in the consultation document the FCA sometimes pays lip service to the original definition, but mostly conveniently forgets the 'payment' part of 'payment instrument' in the definition of 3k. See for example their summary phrasing on page 19:
Limited network exclusion
2.18 Under the PSRs 2009, a business that offers a payment service may be excluded from regulation if its service is based on instruments that can be used only in a limited way to acquire goods or services in certain limited circumstances (often called the “limited network exclusion”) e.g. some gift or store cards.   
2.19 PSD2 aims to standardise the application of the limited network exclusion across the EU, and makes changes to the exclusion which mean it now applies less widely. One limb of the exclusion’s application is narrowed so that it relates to instruments used to acquire a “very” limited range of goods and services (rather than “limited range” set out previously in PSD). A new limb excludes certain instruments provided for social or tax purposes from regulation under the PSRs 2017. Our proposed amendments to Q40 and Q41 in PERG 15 give guidance on the scope of the amended exclusion. 
Then again, the formal notification form does state that the respondent should clarify if the notification tix all the boxes of the law:
Please explain how the product or service falls within the limited network exclusion specified, including details of the following where relevant:
  • the payment instrument; 
  • where and how the payment instrument can be used; 
  • where the customers or users are based; 
  • etc.....
Well, this proposed approach is pretty confusing, so therefore I sent in a reply to the consultation asking to clarify the FCA interpretation of article 3k. In doing so I also referred to the fuel card situation and the set up with chain sales.

Clarify the confusion: are you reading payment instruments as 'instruments' in 3k or not?
We are wondering why the FCA is properly using the delineation payment instruments in a lot of the texts on limited network exclusions, but when it comes down to the actual formulation of excluded activities in Perimeter Guidance, it chooses to forget the word "payments" and sticks to: payment services based on instruments used within a limited network of service providers or for a very limited range of goods or services (“limited network exclusion”). This would create an inconsistency in which the old understanding of limited network is moved towards the new PSD2-interpretations although the legal wording is substantially different.
Should we understand the changed wording to be merely an omission or a situation of intended regulatory scope creep, to include all kind of non payment instruments under the scope of the payments directive? 

When the final document comes in, we'll have a look at the response of the FCA, to see if things have become more clear.

Monday, January 30, 2017

From DNB Coin to ECB Coin...?

About a year ago, it became clear that the Dutch central bank, much like other central banks, was actively experimenting with blockchain technology to further establish pros and cons of distributed ledger technology. It had developed a so-called DNB-coin - a private fork of the bitcoin blockchain - which further reinforced a whole discussion on central bank issued bitcoin-like currencies (Fedcoin as outlined by the blog of JP Koning).

Fast forward to the EU parliament, where last week, rapporteur Cora van Nieuwenhuizen presented a draft Fintech report, that calls on the European Commission to draw up a Fintech Action Plan. And in this plan, under item number 6, the ECB is recommended to launch experimentations with a 'virtual Euro'. I think we may dub this as the call for an ECB-coin.



One can only guess what exactly would be meant here, but my best guess would be that this means the ECB can now freely choose to experiment with methods for distributing digital euro's using advanced blockchain or distributed ledger technology. So would they design it themselves, or involve themselves into market initiatives such as R3, Hyperledger?

Anonymous ECB-coins or not? 
Time will undoubtedly tell how this experiment with ECB-coins will evolve. We should note however that, there is also a European legislative initiative to limit the use of cash. So it appears logical that the cash-limiting initiative could reinforce the development of central bank issued virtual currencies (i.e. euro's on a blockchain).

Those will not be truly anonymous ECB-coins, if you ask me. Close reading of this last legislative proposal, I noticed that anonymous digital currencies (such as the good old digicash) are not truly desired:
In view of the development of cryptocurrencies and the existence of other means of payments ensuring anonymity, an option could be to extend the restrictions to cash payments to all payments ensuring anonymity (cryptocurrencies, payment in kinds, etc.) 
The end of anonimity and begin of pseudonimity 
In sum we will be watching the end of anonimity, but this may not be its true end. I think it would be fairly easy to device new business and payment models where one slices off the good-reputation of a payer/payee (not blacklisted, no terrorist etc) into a pseudonomous, tokenised system that allows payer, payee and all involved financial institutions not to know each other but still transact securely and within the legal parameters as set by society.

Which most likely brings us back to square one: the blockchain.